Posted by: Dirk | August 4, 2014

There is no ‘great bond mispricing’ in the US.

FT Alphaville has a discussion government bond (treasury securities) prices:

The theory is that taper talk prompts dumb money to sell safety, and the smart money — which knows there’s no such thing as underpriced principal safety these days and that taper implies risk-off — to pile into safety at an even faster rate.

However, from a monetary theorist point of view there should be no discussion. The price of US treasury securities is not set by the free market, it is set by arbitrage. This graph from FRED2 shows you 1-Year constant treasury maturity minus federal funds rate:

bonds

The price of treasury securities is set – via arbitrage – by the short-term interest rate on the money market. The different maturities are connected via arbitrage, too. Bond prices and therefore effective yields are not set by central banks of emerging economies and the interactions of supply and demand. They are set by the Fed and by market makers ‘playing’ the yield curve. As long as the Fed’s interest rates are low, the price of US treasury securities will not go anywhere.

That does not mean that you cannot make money in the bond market, obviously. However, I’d argue that the closer the line of the graph above is to zero, the less money you can make. Sovereign Bond markets have been boring (while people shouted: “Hyperinflation”), are boring (“Debasement of the Dollar!”) and will be boring for some time (“The Great Bond Mispricing”). If you want action, look at ‘sovereign bonds’ denominated in foreign currency drafted under foreign law.

German Sunday paper FAS, which belongs to FAZ, has an article named “Hilfe, die Bank will mein Geld nicht” in today’s paper. The title translates to “Help, the bank doesn’t want my money”. The author seems to understand that low interest rates at the ECB are the major cause, but he doesn’t go further and asks why they are so low. Perhaps the German public is not ready yet for the admission that austerity has driven Europe’s economy into a hole, which even ultra-low interest rates can’t fix.

For the first time in the conservative press I see an intent to put forward “endogenous money”, as the author writes:

Zwar ist die verbreitete Vorstellung, Banken könnten nur dann Kredite ausleihen, wenn sie vorher gleichviel Geld bei den Sparern eingesammelt haben, ein populärer Irrtum. “Einlagen- und Kreditgeschäft einer Bank sind nicht unbedingt gekoppelt”, sagt der Bonner Ökonom Martin Hellwig. Banken können sich auf unterschiedliche Weise finanzieren: über Spareinlagen, aber auch über den Geldmarkt oder die Notenbank.

So, it is a popular myth that banks can only make loans after they have acquired savings to the same amount. “Deposit and Credit business of a bank are not necessarily connected”, says Bonn economist Martin Hellwig. Banks can finance in different ways: through savings deposits, but also through the money market or the central bank. I must say that I am amazed to read this. It is a first try to ‘get’ the endogeniety of money, which describes the fact that banks create loans and deposits from nothing. Also, Martin Hellwig is not the reference for endogenous money, and in his 2012 book with Anat Admati he definitely does not understand it:

Banks use both borrowed and unborrowed money to make their loans and other investments. Unborrowed money is the money that a bank has obtained from its owners if it is a private bank or from its shareholders if it is a corporation, along with any profits it has retained.

This is traditional loanable funds theory: bank borrow money to ‘make their loans and other investments’. It is good that Martin Hellwig has changed his opinion, I’m glad he did. However, this should be the start of a big rethink. If those people who held the loanable funds theory dear have been wrong, what about the people who have been right all along? Shouldn’t we be saying: “there was a contest in the discipline of economics to explain how money works, and one side succeeded?” After all, the stuff in the textbooks is still wrong. Olivier Blanchard’s book (2003 edition, but I am very sure it did not change) says:

  • High-powered money is the term used to reflect the fact that the overall supply of money depends in the end on the amount of central bank money (H), or monetary base.

Well, that is wrong. Banks don’t need reserves to make loans. Hence the overall money supply does not depend on central bank money. And economists wrote about it long ago. Here is an example from Knut Wicksell:

wicksell

That seems to be right. When was this written? Well, in 1898. Yes eighteen-98! And Keynes in his early years was a ‘Wicksellian’, writing about the monetary circuit from a balance sheet perspective. Where does the money come from, where does it go, etc. If economics is a science, then it must be about a competition of ideas – which we might call theories if they are more complex – and regardless whether we like it or not, the winner should be made ‘mainstream’, by including this theory in all textbooks, and the runners-up should be put into boxes in textbooks (if they are interesting enough) and books on history of economic thought. After all, we can never be sure that we are right when it comes to social arrangements. Nevertheless, endogenous money is a theory that is able to fit with reality on a lot of things, whereas loanable funds doesn’t.

Loanable funds theory, for instance, assumes that the interest rate is set endogenously in the money/capital market. However, it is quite clear that the ECB, the Fed, the BoJ, the BoE and so on all set interest rates. Then, it can’t be determined in the market. Also, these central banks deny that they control the amount of reserves. Here is the ECB (my highlighting):

Standing facilities aim to provide and absorb overnight liquidity, signal the general monetary policy stance and bound overnight market interest rates. Two standing facilities, which are administered in a decentralised manner by the NCBs, areavailable to eligible counterparties on their own initiative.

Marginal lending facility

Counterparties can use the marginal lending facility to obtain overnight liquidity from the NCBs against eligible assets. The interest rate on the marginal lending facility normally provides a ceiling for the overnight market interest rate.

Deposit facility

Counterparties can use the deposit facility to make overnight deposits with the NCBs. The interest rate on the deposit facility normally provides a floor for the overnight market interest rate.

The marginal lending facility is open 30 minutes after the closing of the market. If banks borrow more reserves after markets closed, there is nobody at the ECB or its member central banks who could counter the increase in reserves.

I sincerely hope that in the coming months we will see a wider discussion of endogenous money as a description for how banks work. It will then become clear that repayment of loans destroys money in the form of deposits, and that this is what is holding the European periphery, nay, the whole euro zone back. If we as European consumers have less deposits in our bank accounts, how are we supposed to buy more stuff? If we don’t, then unemployment will stay above 10% in the euro zone and the slump continues. This is an unhealthy situation brought about by ‘the free market’, and if economic policy does not intervene then the weak economy will continue. What this means for European politics should be clear to everybody (article by Reuters):

French far-right leader Marine Le Pen would reach the final round of a presidential election if voters were to vote now, winning more votes than any mainstream party in the first round, a poll showed on Thursday.

The survey by pollster IFOP showed Le Pen winning 26 percent of all votes in round one of the two-round election, versus 17 percent for either President Francois Hollande or his more popular prime minister, Manuel Valls.

The next presidential election is in 2017.

The end of Europe as we know it is what it could mean.

In a NYT article, Laurence Kotlikoff gives us his account of economics as it used to be: a science to confuse the public about what a government can and can’t do:

HOUSEHOLDS can’t spend, on a continuing basis, more than they earn. Countries can’t either, at least not over the long run. But countries can certainly leave the bill for their current spending to the young and to future generations. Official borrowing is the old-fashioned way to do this: Sell Treasury bonds, and other securities, and spend the proceeds. But borrowing in broad daylight has a drawback: The more you do it, the more lenders worry about repayment, and the more interest they charge for their loans.

This might sound very logical, except that there is a problem: a government is not a household. Why not? Well, households don’t have an account at the central bank, as the US Treasury has. Households also cannot sell treasury (or household) bonds that are risk free, because if push comes to shove the central bank will buy these bonds on the secondary market to an extent that all actors on the primary market will engage in arbitrage. If banks buy treasury bonds (and bills and notes) directly from the government, and they know that they can turn around and sell them to the Federal Reserve Bank for a profit, then there should be no doubt about one thing: the US government cannot go bankrupt. Which household can say that?

Kotlikoff continues:

The fiscal gap — the difference between our government’s projected financial obligations and the present value of all projected future tax and other receipts — is, effectively, our nation’s credit card bill.

Right. If the US government spends more than its tax income in the future, then it is charged to ‘our nation’s credit card bill’ today. As I have described above, the US Terasury does not have to rely on bank loans or credit card companies to finance its expenditures (above taxes). Let’s jump to his conclusion:

What we confront is not just an economics problem. It’s a moral issue. Will we continue to hide most of the bills we are bequeathing our children? Or will we, at long last, systematically measure all the bills and set about reducing them?

That is utter nonsense. We will not bequeath any bill to our children. If government spends more than it collects in taxes, it issues treasury bonds. These treasury bonds are bequeathed to our children, too. Somebody will be quite rich, as there are quite a lot of government bonds outstanding. Inequality can be a problem, because the future tax payers transfer money to those that are holding the bonds. Conveniently, Kotlikoff overlooks this issue.

The framing used by Kotlikoff to talk about US government debt is misleading. It is based on false analogies, starting with the idea that government spends just like a household. One could argue for lower social security payments, but not on the basis that the US government can’t afford it.

Posted by: Dirk | July 28, 2014

The ECB on money: enhancing monetary analysis

The ECB discusses money in its paper “Enhancing monetary analysis”. Chapter 1 is titled “The role of money in the economy and central bank policy”. It was prepared by Giacomo Carboni, Boris Hofmann and Fabrizio Zampolli. The ECB distinguishes inside and outside money.

Banknotes and coins – or in short, currency – are normally the most secure form of money. They are issued by the central bank and/or government, which vouches for their general acceptability and the stability of their purchasing power. Equally safe are the deposits held at the central bank, normally available only to banks. Banks use them both as a means to settle payments among themselves and as a reserve to meet unusual demands for withdrawals of currency by their depositors. Along with the currency in circulation, the deposits held at the central bank constitute the so-called “monetary base”, “central bank money” or “outside money”.5 This money is usually “legal tender”, which means that any potential creditor is obliged by law to accept it in settlement of any debt.6

5 It is known as “outside” money to highlight the fact that it is created by the public sector as opposed to the private sector (and could be in principle controlled more easily) or as “high-powered” money to stress the fact that it constitutes the basis of the entire monetary pyramid whereby banks – by operating a fractional reserve system – create a volume of media of exchange that is a multiple of the money created by the central bank.
6 Importantly, the exact definition of “legal tender” may differ from country to country.

The second paragraph are the footnotes of the first. A different term for central bank money would be reserves. The paragraph on legal tender is somewhat interesting. Footnote 6 says it may differ from country to country. Nevertheless, tax payments ultimately are made in reserves (or what the ECB calls central bank money). Sadly, the ECB does not mention this and completely erases the fiscal part from the whole story. That probably has created the blind spot which led to the creation of a euro zone in which sovereign bonds were not risk free. The ECB continues then describes endogenous money (my highlighting):

Deposits issued by private banks, which are what most individuals and companies have access to, are held for the safety and the convenience that they offer over currency. Not only are they less subject to the risk of theft, but they also offer the convenience of a range of payment options, such as cheques (now less common than in the past), debit and credit cards, and electronic transfers. Other types of securities are also used as a means of payment – for example, certain IOUs issued by private non-financial corporations and widely traded on financial markets (commercial paper), or units in money market funds. The overall amount of money in circulation is, to a large extent, determined by the behaviour of banks and the (profit-seeking) behaviour and interaction of a myriad of private agents.

This, I think, is correct. The amount of money (=deposits in banks) in circulation is largely determined by banks lending to the private sector. What does not determine the amount of money (=deposits in banks) is the central bank, which is in the business of setting the interest through, as the ECB says, variations of the amount of reserves (=central bank deposits of banks). The text goes on describing the money multiplier, but then backing away from this concept:

However, as recently pointed out by Goodhart (2010), a major drawback of the money multiplier approach to money supply analysis is its entirely mechanistic character, which does not offer an account of the behaviour of the central bank, private banks or the private sector money-holders. The pace of financial deregulation and financial innovation over the last few decades has certainly challenged the notion of a stable money multiplier. Also, in times of crisis, money multipliers may prove to be highly unstable and hence may be a poor guide to predicting the effect of monetary policy measures on the money supply. This has become manifest during the global financial crisis, where the massive expansion of base money by central banks was not reflected in the development of broader monetary aggregates because of a collapse of money multipliers when banks were hoarding reserves.

So, the view of the ECB of money is correct. There are some parts omitted from the picture, like the idea that taxes drive money and not price stability, but the description of the two monetary circuits – bank deposits and central bank deposits – is correct. One would have hoped for some more detailed descriptions of interbank clearing and fiscal operations, but there is some good literature (like Fullwiler 2008 and Wray’s MMT Primer) out there which explain it from a balance sheet perspective. Since the BoE and other institutions and academics agree with this, maybe we have New New Consensus?

El Pais reports that the Spanish government has sold Catalunya Banc for €1.1 billion to BBVA. The newspaper writes:

Esta operación supone que los contribuyentes pierden definitivamente 11.839 millones de euros, una cantidad que se acerca a los recortes en sanidad y educación hasta 2013, que suman 13.800 millones.

La entidad, que llegó a ser la cuarta mayor caja de España, tenía unas ayudas directas del Estado de 12.050 millones y otros 572 millones inyectados posteriormente por el FROB para la venta de la cartera de hipotecas tóxicas. En total ha puesto 12.622 millones y recibirá 783 millones con la venta porque solo tiene el 66% de Catalunya Banc. La operación incrementará el déficit público porque el FROB valoró en sus libros a Catalunya Banc en 1.858 millones y percibirá 783.

So, the tax payers lose definitively €11.8 billion, which is about the full amount of cuts in health and education until 2013, which stand at €13.8 billion. The bank, which was the fourth biggest of Spain, had direct aid from the government of €12.05 billion and another €572 million from the sale of the toxic mortgages from the ‘Fund for Orderly Bank Restructuring’ (FROB). The public deficit will go up as a result of this operation because FROB valued Catalunya Banc at €1.848 billion and will receive €783 million.

This is what happens when you bail-out a bank that is not illiquid, but insolvent. I think that there needs to be a discussion why you use €11.5 billion for bank restructuring, which then become a definite loss, and not for propping up health care, education or other government services which have been cut harshly over the last years. The Spanish governments (Zapatero, Rajoy) had a political choice to increase taxes or cut government spending, to bail-out their insolvent banks or to let them fail in an orderly way (yes, there are rules for that), they had the possibility to press for a European solution because Spanish banks owed German banks hundreds of billions of euros on the interbank market, they could have pressed for a less harsh interpretation of the deficit rules, etc. Whatever they did, the results have basically been zero. Yes, they kept Spain in the euro zone, but that is the status quo and it is unclear whether it was a good idea to stay in, given that the institutions (fiscal rules, banking regulation) are what they are.

Reality is constructed through politics, and politics can be quite one-sided. That, it seems to me, is the lesson to be learned from Spain, where creditors are saved once and again at huge fiscal costs while youth unemployment stands at 54%. Spain’s GDP today is still below that of 2007.

Posted by: Dirk | July 17, 2014

A fresh look at Positive Money

The World Economics Association has featured an article on Positive Money in its latest newsletter. Let me discuss some aspects of this text because I think that there are still many open questions regarding both the analysis and the policy recommendations. The article starts its analytical part like this:

Now, which are the malfunctions of the present monetary system?

1. Money is created as debt.Today, money comes into existence by debt creation when commercial banks borrow from central banks and when governments, producers or consumers borrow from commercial banks. Thus, the money supply of the economy can only be maintained if the private or public economic actors get into debt. Economic growth requires a proportionate increase in the money supply in order to avoid deflation that would paralyze business, but an increase in the quantity of money involves a simultaneous increase in debt. This way, economic actors run into danger of excessive indebtedness and bankruptcy. It is not necessary to say that overindebtedness causes serious problems to societies and individuals in the face of the ongoing debt crisis.

As I find myself in disagreement with almost all sentences, let me tackle them one by one. (I am doing this because I think that the analysis is flawed, not because I don’t like the conclusions.) The first sentence of the answer is correct, but imprecise. What is meant by money? Money-reserves created by the central bank? Money-deposits created by banks? Money-deposit certificates created by money market funds? As we start here with “money” being highlighted – although not defined – and loan demand and interest rates neglected we’re roughly in the Monetarist camp.

The next sentence could have cleared things up – but it doesn’t because the readers are not experts in monetary theory and don’t know that “when commercial banks borrow from central banks” it is central bank money (reserves) that is created while “when governments, producers or consumers borrow from commercial banks” it is bank money (deposits). And, it is wrong to put government in one list with the private sector. The government, while often able to do so to some extent, actually does not “borrow” from commercial banks. It is selling government bonds. Selling government bonds is different from getting a loan because in most monetary system the government is not in danger of a failed auction. Selling government bonds in countries with a sovereign currency always succeeds. Exceptions are few, and only the euro zone with its no-bail-out clause chose a difference path (which Draghi corrected in the meantime). So, while a loan is not always granted, a government bond is always placed in the market, and if banks don’t buy it the central bank will (if not in the primary than in the secondary market). I find it quite wrong to place government, which is issuing riskless assets in almost all sovereign money systems, in one category with private sector loans, which are prone to default. Especially since government bonds are promises to pay central bank money (reserves) while private sector bank loans only promise to pay deposits. Next sentence:

Thus, the money supply of the economy can only be maintained if the private or public economic actors get into debt.

With no clear definition of a money supply it is impossible to evaluate whether this is true or not. The next question is whether that “or” is an “and/or” or an “exclusive or” (in a closed economy private sector wealth equals public sector debt). As general as was written, the sentence is wrong. If the private sector keeps its share of loans steady, then no increase in public debt is necessary to maintain the money supply (if that includes deposits). Also, a country with a current account surplus can have a rise in deposits and hence the money supply while both the private sector and the public sector run a surplus, meaning that the private sector saves more than it invests and the government’s tax income is higher than its spending. Next sentence:

Economic growth requires a proportionate increase in the money supply in order to avoid deflation that would paralyze business, but an increase in the quantity of money involves a simultaneous increase in debt.

That’s nice, here we can check the available data to see whether it is true that “economic growth requires a proportionate increase in the money supply”. Here is the data for the US via FRED2:

fredgraph

Well, the consumer price index change from year to year is inflation (fat black line), and it is positive almost all of the time. However, some monetary aggregates (M1, M3, MB) had negative growth rates from time to time. Also, inflation in the late 1970s does not correlate with movement in the monetary aggregate (M1). A rise in the monetary base (cash plus reserves) in the last recession also did not coincide with the inflation rate. Comparing all those colored line with the inflation rate, I can hardly make out which one is proportionately increasing in relation to the inflation rate. Can you? (If you can, you’d be a monetarist.)

Now for the second part of that sentence (“an increase in the quantity of money involves a simultaneous increase in debt”) I can not see how that can be true. Money is debt, sure, but not all debt is money. Government can create huge debts, which would allow the private sector to use the additional deposits (from incomes paid by the public sector) to pay down its own debt. This would shrink the private sector debt and therefore money and increase the amounts of government bonds, which are not counted as “money”. So, an increase in (public) debt can decrease the quantity of money. Probably this is part of the Japanese story of the last 20+ years.

“This way, economic actors run into danger of excessive indebtedness and bankruptcy.” Well, except that a government with a sovereign currency cannot go bankrupt. The case of Japan shows that government spending can prop up an economy is the private sector decides to pay down debt. Technically there is not a problem with the monetary system, quite the opposite. One just has to use it right. Also, “excessive indebtedness” is very vague. What is the yardstick? Sure, we can outlaw any loans, but then you can only start production if are very, very rich. Only the super-rich do not have to worry about “excessive indebtedness”.

It is not necessary to say that overindebtedness causes serious problems to societies and individuals in the face of the ongoing debt crisis.

Hmmm. This is very one-sided. After 1945, many Western societies had good growth rates. Many firms borrowed from banks to start and expand businesses, households borrowed to buy houses, etc. Now there are some countries that suffer, but they are mostly inside the euro zone (Spain, Ireland, Greece, Cyprus, etc.), which is a special case due to the lack of exchange rate adjustment. The UK was a case of self-imposed austerity, which was not necessary under the monetary system. Iceland defaulted on its bank debt and seems to be doing more than OK.

Going through the rest of the text I encounter many expressions which I think are just plain wrong: “interest has to be paid on all the money in circulation” (I pay no interest on my cash, do you? And banks can acquire cash from the central bank by selling government bonds to it), “Interest is a subsidy to the banks because the account money they create is handled as legal tender” (no, it is not), “In a sovereign money system the unnecessarily complicated two-level banking system would be replaced by a single-level system, in which money is no longer backed by reserves” (money is not “backed” by reserves today), and last but not least, “the existing bad framework that governments attempt to straighten out with evermore complex regulation consisting of the fractional reserve system, …” (we don’t have a fractional reserve system because banks cannot lend out reserves).

While I believe that many Vollgeld (100% money) supporters have good intentions, I’m afraid that their analysis once and again builds on a neoclassical world view which should have been discarded decades ago. Building on flawed foundations, the new financial house will be unable to wheather the storm – like the euro, which has also been build on neoclassical foundations (crowding-out, monetarism). Nevertheless, there are still many issues that are of shared concern: the role of private banks and financial markets in the crisis, the lack of concern for the real economy (jobs) and ecology, and political economy and macroeconomic problems resulting from a very unequal income and wealth distribution.

To sum it up: I am not convinced that the economic malaise in some European countries has been caused by inherent flaws in our monetary system and I am not convinced that these flaws cannot be remedied in the existing framework (through higher capital requirements, for instance). Yes, bank loans financing real estate have caused the boom (and the bust), but without those loans we would have had lots of unemployment and very likely negative growth rates. Of course, fiscal spending could have been used to fill the gap in demand, but the politicians (and economists) did not want to touch that policy except for that brief time during 2009. I cannot see how we need a new monetary system in order to clean up the mess in Europe. There is much to be done, but from the macroeconomic perspective freeing us from the fiscal constraints should be enough to return Europe to growth and prosperity shared by all Europeans.

Posted by: Dirk | July 17, 2014

Wicksell (1898) on financial crises

Knut Wicksell in his 1898 [1936] Interest and Prices discusses financial booms and busts over some pages in chapter 7 (87-101). He discusses three possible mechanisms which can lead to a rise in prices of capital goods. These are always discussed as changes in relative prices given some level of loan demand. The section name is a hint: B. Simplest Hypothesis. Variations of the Rate of Interest when the Market Situation Remains otherwise Unaltered. On page 92 he writes:

If railway companies could issue debentures at 3 per cent, instead of 4 per cent., they would be able, ceteris paribus, to pay almost 33.1/3 per cent, more for all their requirements: 4 per cent, on 100 million marks comes to the same thing as 3 per cent on 133.1/3 million marks.

A fall in the interest rate thus has an effect on some goods prices, those that are used as inputs in the production of railways and railway equipment. Prices of inputs, land rents and wages go up, but so does the price of whatever the entrepreneur produces. So, the entrepreneur will pay more and more for his inputs since the rising prices given some interest rate increase his profits. As long as the interest rate remains at its level, prices move up cumulatively. This is classic Wicksell, only price effects at work and no changes in demand or supply. This whole episode reminds me a bit of Tobin’s q. However, Wicksell does not assume that changes in relative prices cause any quantity adjustments, as Tobin said. Wicksell continues to discuss house prices and expectations (p. 96):

An abnormally large amount of investment will now probably be devoted to durable goods. There may result a relative over- production of such things as houses and a relative under-production of other commodities. [...]

We may go further. The upward movement of prices will in some measure “create its own draught”. When prices have been rising steadily for some time, entrepreneurs will begin to reckon on the basis not merely of the prices already attained, but of a further rise in prices. The effect on supply and demand is clearly the same as that of a corresponding easing of credit.

The second paragraph clearly is about expectations. Wicksell notes that the effect of expectations of rising house prices have the same effect on the market as ‘a corresponding easing of credit’. This is especially interesting in the European context, where real estate bubbles had developed in some countries (Spain, Ireland) but not in others. Finally, on page 97/98, Wicksell takes on speculation:

The matter takes on an entirely different aspect in the case where the market is under the influence of speculation proper. Goods are now bought, not merely to be passed on to other producers and to be distributed to consumers by the normal methods, but to be hastily disposed of to other speculators. The time element, which normally plays a decisive part, now ceases to be of any great significance; and it becomes impossible to make even the roughest kind of estimate of the probable rise in prices. Insecure sentiment governs the market; as prices continue to soar and profits are easily earned, the movement may rapidly reach fever-point. There is almost no limit to the rise in prices in spite of the fact that credit becomes more and more expensive. But when prices ultimately come to rest, and the prospect of further profits disappears, the credit position is so strained and the rate of interest is so high as immediately to bring about a contrary movement, which proceeding in analogous fashion may rapidly drag down prices even below their normal level.

The idea that prices are overshooting in the boom and undershooting in the bust phase of the business cycle is widely understood today, of course. Nevertheless, Wicksell’s 1898 monograph might still be a good starting point for those interested in interest and prices and other things macroeconomic, like endogenous money.

Posted by: Dirk | July 15, 2014

Diagrams & Dollars: Modern Money Educational Video

I like this video, but I am afraid that those who did not yet think through modern money will need to watch this in slow motion. Working with metaphors is a good idea, but then this can only be a teaser. As that, it works quite well. It reminds me of the good old Phillips machine.

Posted by: Dirk | July 15, 2014

(Book review) Freedom from National Debt

Frank Newman was a CEO and chairman of commercial banks in both the US and China, and he also was Deputy Secretary of the U.S. Treasury Department. Perhaps it surprises that the cover of his book features the following inscription:

Why U.S. Treasury Securities

  • never have to be paid off in total by taxpayers
  • cannot present the problems of eurozone nations
  • are safer than money
  • represent savings for millions of investors

and why America does not need to fear “national debt”

His book Freedom from National Debt makes all these claims and more, backing them up with an insider’s perspective on the working of federal balance sheets. The book focusses on U.S. treasuries and popular misconceptions of the public. With a slim 77 pages it is a quick read, suitable for everyone interested in a confirmation of the view that Post-Keynesians and MMTers hold of the fiscal side of the economy. The only point I find myself in strong disagreement with is chapter 7: why foreign ownership of treasuries is not a problem. Well, from the financial point of view there is nothing wrong with foreign ownership of U.S. treasuries, but from the real point of view this translates into more and more exports of goods and services. While this would create employment, it is a drain of production that otherwise could be consumed at home. It is only fair that those countries that export more than they import to/from the US build up stocks of U.S. treasuries, and it is not a problem if people know what’s happening and are aware that US economic policy today means that more of GDP produced tomorrow will be sent abroad. In times of a depressed economy, this might not be a big issue, but in times of a booming economy there might be some inflationary pressures.

Let’s not worry about the problems of the future upswing while the US economy still has an employment to population ratio way below where it was before the crisis. For those looking for an insider’s view on fiscal management, this book can be recommended.

Posted by: Dirk | July 14, 2014

(Book review) In praise of debt

I have thought long and hard about whether to review a book here which is available in German (Lob der Schulden) and French (Éloge de la dette) only. Here it is. Nathalie Sarthou-Lajus published her book in 2012 in French and 2013 in German. All references are taken from the German version. Sarthou-Lajus thinks that debt is not bad, but can be a good thing. There are some things which you cannot pay for, and this does not have to be something negative (p. 13). Being in debt can unsettle an individual, but that does not have to lead to bankruptcy. She thinks that debt is part of every human relationship, and moving into the creditor position by giving something up can lead to a life of freedom. After the equation of debt with evil, this is a very refreshing perspective.

On page 31, Sarthou-Lajus writes that individual freedom is not enough to ensure the well-being of everyone. The government, the nation has the debt of granting assistance to those in need. Historically, these rights of individuals against their nation was added after the French Revolution. After the Great Financial Crisis, we would have to rethink the relationship between state and individual along these lines. She picks up this line of thought again on page 47, arguing that although the subjects of democracy can learn to become autonomous, they will never become truly independent and autarkic. A subject would not be self-alienated just because it depends on others. This, I think, is a defense of the social.

Sarthou-Lajus ends her very thoughtful book with a praise of debt, which can connect individuals over generations and build a social fabric. However, she also says that we need to be free from some debts, to give up on relationships, in order to give some new impulses to our lives and flourish according to our own wishes. I am tempted to say that what holds for individuals also holds for nations, but fallacies of composition would surely arise, making things more complicated for whole societies.

Older Posts »

Categories

Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 137 other followers